Tim Lucas, 919-613-8084, tdlucas@duke.edu
Note to editors: Martin D. Smith is available for additional comment at (919) 613-8028 or marsmith@duke.edu. Ling Huang is available at (860) 486-3272 or ling.huang@uconn.edu.
DURHAM, N.C. -- By identifying the most efficient fishing practices and behaviors, a new model developed by economists at 91社区福利 and the University of Connecticut could help fishermen land larger paychecks while reducing the risk of fishery depletion.
鈥淲e鈥檙e not talking about a trivial improvement. In some cases, we found that identifying the most efficient practices led to a 20 percent annual increase in total revenues if the fishery is managed differently,鈥 said Martin D. Smith, professor of environmental economics at Duke鈥檚 Nicholas School of the Environment.
鈥淯nder perfect conditions, you could see up to a 49 percent increase in profits on average,鈥 he said.
The empirical bioeconomic model developed by Smith and Ling Huang, assistant professor of economics at the University of Connecticut, is the first of its kind. It was created using six years of previously unavailable fine-scale fishing data from the North Carolina shrimp fishery, provided to the researchers by the North Carolina Division of Marine Fisheries.
鈥淓very single vessel that went out was tracked -- what it caught, when it fished, what price it sold its catch for, and what equipment was used,鈥 Smith said. 鈥淲e also tracked daily weather conditions, fuel prices, fishery closures and other external factors that affect fishermen鈥檚 decisions of whether to fish or not.鈥
Smith and Huang analyzed the flood of data using recently developed econometric modeling techniques to identify which individual fishing practices and decisions led to profitable and sustainable catches, and which led to low returns and overexploitation.
The results yielded some surprises.
鈥淐onventional wisdom says that congestion -- having too many boats out at the same time -- is bad because it makes it harder for individual fishermen to catch at the level they鈥檙e used to, so profits drop,鈥 Smith said. 鈥淲e found this is true in the short run, but there鈥檚 a potential long-term benefit fishery managers may be overlooking.
鈥淲hen people鈥檚 profits drop due to congestion, they tend to fish less. This means more of the shrimp left in the water get to grow to larger sizes and can be harvested later in the season for higher prices,鈥 he said. 鈥淪o in some cases, congestion can actually increase potential late-season profits and reduce the risk of fishery depletion.鈥
Smith and Huang鈥檚 study focused primarily on the open-access N.C. shrimp fishery, but insights from it could help improve how other fisheries are managed as well.
鈥淲e鈥檙e leaving substantial profits on the table due to the way we鈥檙e managing many fisheries,鈥 Smith said. 鈥淭he standard one-size-fits-all management approach of allocating sustainable catch limits to individual fishermen on an annual basis is not universally efficient. In some cases, it鈥檚 actually counterproductive because it forces fishermen into a 鈥榬ace to fish鈥 early in the season that leads to falling profits, overexploitation and, eventually, tragedy of the commons.鈥
The key to avoiding this, Huang said, is to match the management approach of each individual fishery to the daily, fine-scale dynamics of its fishermen, its seasonal patterns, and the life history of the species being harvested.
鈥淥ur analysis shows there鈥檚 a sweet spot between having too much bureaucracy -- such as daily quotas -- and too little. That鈥檚 the spot we have to hit if we want to maximize profits and sustainable catches,鈥 she said. 鈥淭o get there, you have to dig down to the fine scale.鈥
Smith and Huang published their study in this month鈥檚 issue of the peer-reviewed journal American Economic Review. Funding came from the NOAA Center for Sponsored Ocean Research (grant # NA05NOS4781197). Huang is a former student of Smith鈥檚. She earned her Ph.D. in environmental economics from Duke in 2009.
###
CITATION: 鈥淭he Dynamic Efficiency Costs of Common-Pool Resource Exploitation,鈥 by Ling Huang and Martin D. Smith. American Economic Review, Dec. 3, 2014. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.104.12.4071.
漏 2014 Duke Office of News & Communications
615 Chapel Drive, Box 90563, Durham, NC 27708-0563
(919) 684-2823; After-hours phone (for reporters on deadline): (919) 812-6603